Loading

Annals of Biometrics and Biostatistics

Economic and Clinical Covariates of Workers’ Delayed Treatment Seeking Behavior in Bangladesh

Original Research | Open Access | Volume 5 | Issue 2

  • 1. Department of Economics, Shahjalal University of Science & Technology, Bangladesh
+ Show More - Show Less
Corresponding Authors
Syed Hasanuzzaman, Department of Economics, Shahjalal University of Science & Technology, Sylhet, Bangladesh, Tel: +4407398343857;
Abstract

Delayed treatment bears no good results other than shielding financial loss temporarily. But the long-term effects can be dangerous, both for recovery and budgetary burden. Still more than 72% of Bangladeshi workers take the risk of not rushing to healthcare centers. Almost 30% of them were found making delays beyond 3 days and around 21% wait more than 5 days. A discrete choice model in a dynamic setting found misperception about natural healing and a common dissatisfaction to healthcare service to influence workers’ treatment seeking behavior in Bangladesh in addition to loss of income, cost of treatment and workplace rigidities. Weak health infrastructure and local constraints are also worsening such behavior.

Keywords

Delay ; Healthcare seeking behaviour ; Workers ; Discrete choice ; Endogeneity.

CITATION

Hasanuzzaman S (2020) Economic and Clinical Covariates of Workers’ Delayed Treatment Seeking Behavior in Bangladesh. Ann Biom Biostat 5(2): 1037.

ABBREVIATIONS

2SRI: 2-Stage Residual Inclusion; IV: Instrumental Variable; BDT: Bangladeshi Taka (Currency of Bangladesh)

INTRODUCTION

Self-determined delay in treatment seeking is still less addressed in developing countries where health insurances are almost non-existing and healthcare system suffers multidimensional inefficiencies. Prompt healthcare seeking can reduce treatment cost through early diagnosis, improved treatment compliance and short recovery period. Regardless of the consequences people are found delaying in seeking early treatment for poverty [1]; cost of treatment [2,3]; socio-economic status, gender, age, type of illness and quality of health care [4,5]; religious and traditional superstitions, cultural customs [6,7]; and as such. Non-unionized labors, job contracts with traditional medical allowancing instead of health insurance and inefficient health care system have eventually made out-of-pocket health expenditures common to almost all earning persons in Bangladesh. The weak insurance market works privately offering weaker schemes in health care. A feeling of losing real income may be leading working people to sub-optimal treatment seeking behavior. Besides, existing dual health care system, where the same physicians can operate privately side by side being engaged in public jobs [8], has resulted in inefficient service and widespread dissatisfaction among care seekers [9]. Health seeking behavior can be explained by the process models [4,7], as exercised by Conner and Norman [10,11], that emphasize the process of illness response. Alternatively, end point or pathway models in health, such as the health belief model and Anderson’s health behavior model, describe utilization of the formal system and thereby evaluate health care seeking behavior. However, household income and cost of treatment overpower most of the factors determining health care demand when out-of-pocket health expenditures are obvious and when we are judging first time care seeking for any illness or injury. Also, quality of health care and illness type are vital in this regard. Rucker, Brennan, and Burstin [12] compared relative importance of various clinical and socioeconomic factors behind delay in seeking emergency care. This study aims to extend the discussion for delay in workers’ illness and injuries from an economic point of view considering financial constraints and inefficiency in healthcare service in a dynamic optimization setting.

Absence of labor unions, exclusion of occupational health from primary healthcare and lack of government initiatives resulted in a poor occupational health in Bangladesh. Few formal workers receive negligible lump-sum medical allowances that cannot reduce out-of-pocket health expenditures to any great extent. This causes delay in treatment, under or informal treatment, and even no treatment with obvious long run effects. Workplace accidents were responsible for 1,292 workers’ death in 2017 in Bangladesh (Bangladesh Occupational Safety, Health and environment foundation, OSHE, 2017). Workplace hazards like chemical, ergonomic and physical hazards are generated by workers’ interactions with various chemical and biological agents, machines, extreme temperature, atmospheric pressure, load lifting, smoke, noise, stress, other workers and so on. Such accidents have cost lives of about 12,864 workers along with 11,767 workplace injuries in the ten-year period from 2008 to 2017 (OSHE, 2017). Lacks in safety measures, enforcement of national and international laws, and awareness are reasons for these deaths and injuries. Work related injuries and illness are not only causing individual losses but also incurring productivity drops in industries, threats to public health and wellbeing, and uncertainty to smooth supply.

Total health expenditures in Bangladesh have increased from $1.1 billion in 1997 to $4.1 billion in 2012 with a real annual growth rate of 8% and with an increase of out-of-pocket payment by households from 55.9% of these expenditures in 1997 to 63.3% in 2012 [13]. There are over 600 hospitals in the country, 16,438 community clinic and health centres and 30,000 satellite clinics for child and maternal healthcare (Centre for Research and Information, CRI, 2018, ‘Bangladesh, towards better healthcare’). Public facilities are at the core of the pluralistic health care system in Bangladesh accommodating health workers, drug administration and community clinics in community level, health centers or complexes in union level, general hospitals and specialized hospitals in district level, and Post Graduate Medical Institutes with specialized healthcare centers as tertiary level healthcare [14]. The private for-profit health care facilities are urban oriented and rapidly increasing with growing inefficiency in public health care facilities (the number of registered private for-profit facilities increased from 1038 in 2007 to 5023 in 2017, [13]). Also, there are non-profit private health care providers, mainly operated by non-government organizations (NGO), along with village doctors, pharmacists and a wide variety of informal and unqualified providers. Lack of professionals, absence and lack of empathy among doctors and nurses, drug shortage, waiting time, travel hazard, etc. contributed to the low use of public health facilities [15,16]. Many studies showed use of unqualified health providers to be greater than the public facilities by many fold [17]. Also, medical tourism from Bangladesh is increasing rapidly. More than 2,00,000 Bangladeshis travelled India for medical purposes in 2017 and the number is rising very fast [18]. In this perspective this study explores why working people are neglecting their treatment needs in Bangladesh.

MATERIALS AND METHODS

Theoretical background

We assume that household utility, U, depends on consumption, C, and worker’s illness and injuries, D (thus, U = U(C, D) with U_{c}^{i}> 0 and U_{D}^{i}> 0). Out-of-pocket treatment expenditures cause income losses that lead to lower consumption and hence, lower utility. The second element, D (worker’s illness and injuries), also decreases household utility because of reduction in worker’s marginal utility from consumption, [19] \left ( \frac{\partial ^{2}U\left ( C,D \right )}{\partial C \partial D }< 0 \right ).Obviously worker’s health deficit, F, will depend on his/her illness and injuries, D, in addition to overall health condition, X^{1}\left ( so, F=F\left ( X,D \right ) \right ) with F_{x}^{1}< 0 and F_{D}^{1}> 0. we are  adopting X includes worker’s age, gender, education, history of medication, standard assumptions for our intertemporal utility function, U, and health deficit function, F. We also assume that health deficits caused by worker’s illness and injury, D, can be stopped by a health investment, h, [20]. Workers also derive utility from health investment for regaining marginal utility from consumption. Both these effects explain important influence of health investment (or treatment), h, on health deficit function, F \left ( \frac{\partial F\left ( X,D \right )}{\partial h }< 0\right ). we adopt the separability assumption between worker utility from consumption and from the cost of health protection. However, delay in treatment, d, always causes belated recovery or greater loss in marginal consumption, which can lead to higher cost of health protection. For simplicity we suppose d to be a downward shifter of the utility function. For instant treatment, i.e. for d → 0, treatment efficiency is the highest and it decreases with d, lim_{d\rightarrow \infty } \frac{\partial F\left ( X,D \right )}{\partial h }< -\infty. The problem involves continuous choices of consumption accompanied by discrete treatment delay option to maximize worker’s utility over a period, t=0,........,T. that can be presented as:max_{C,d}\sum_{t=0}^{T}\beta ^{t}\left [ U\left ( C_{t},D \right )-F\left ( X,D \right )-\delta d_{t}\right ]. We measured d in days to visit health care after symptoms of illness or injury were revealed. Thus, d = 0 means instant care seeking, = 1 refers to first visit within 2 days of symptoms, = 3 indicates visit within 4 days and = 4 is for delay beyond 4 days. However, \delta \in \left ( 0,1 \right ) can be assumed as disutility to work due to illness or injury. Obviously, a worker has to optimize the choices about consumption and treatment delay each period with respect to period specific financial constraints, C_{t}\leq M_{t}, where M_{t} is the beginning of period t consumable resources or wealth. We can think of a simple wealth accumulation relationship defined by last period’s savings (M_{t-1}-C_{t-1}), labor income (Y_{t-1}) and treatment cost (h_{t-1}). The Bellman solution produces optimal consumption rule, but the value function will not be globally concave in the presence of discrete choice [21]. Following Iskhakov et al. [22] we can predict a kink point at any value M=M_{t} where the worker takes the decision to treat. An analytical solution is suggested by Iskhakov et al. [22] that evaluates the value function at the kink point, the point that differentiates the value functions by \left ( \delta +h \right )^{2}.

Beyond the above exposition we suppose workplace constraints and individual perceptions forcing treatment delays. Along with income, cost of treatment, and nature of illness or injury, there are influences from work related issues for which workers can show random treatment delay behavior. In the absence of labor union and health insurance workers suffer financial constraints to make out-of-pocket treatment expenditures, loss of income due to medical leave, and even difficulties in achieving leave permissions. Self-decided delay in seeking treatment not only signifies individual attitude towards health seeking behaviour but also captures contributions from collective learning and community impact on individual’s cognitive development. The working peers can influence individual perceptions towards health care efficiency and cost.???????Data???????

Bangladesh household income and expenditure survey, 2016 17 (HIES 2016-17), the latest nationwide survey by Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics (BBS) using a stratified two-stage sample design and capturing data on household poverty, standard of living, health and education status, and so on from 46,080 households, is used in this study. Among 44,378 people who have reported to be working 7,602 reported that they were ill within last 30 days.

Econometric model

A multinomial logistic regression model is deployed to examine the factors responsible for self-determining delay in treatment seeking behaviour by working class comparing four distinct groups: immediate care seekers (who make visits loosing no time), seekers of treatment soon (within two days of symptom), late (within three to four days) and very late (more than four days). Empirical studies select the scale purposively in accordance to the research environment. Chen, Rizzo and Rodriguez [2] used delaying or forgoing needed treatment within a year as a dichotomous variable as they were examining its health effects among US civilian non-institutionalized population. Abuduxike et al. [1] used the same definition for a 5-year span for people of Northern Cyprus. In contrary, Romay-Barja et al. [23] defined delay whenever treatment was sought beyond 24 hours of symptoms as they were judging the case of Malaria in Equatorial Guinea. For urinary incontinence among Chinese women a longer delay was defined by Wu et al. [24] if there was no treatment seeking within 3 years. Rucker, Brennan and Burstin [12] used number of days symptoms were persisting to define four groups: 0 days, 1-2 days, 3-6 days, and ≥ 7 days as they were examining delay in seeking emergency care in five international hospitals.

The socio-demographic approach to healthcare utilization behavior, as addressed by Anderson [25], highlights its determinants as age, sex, education, occupation, ethnicity, socioeconomic status, and income [26, 27]. However, Bice, Eichhorn, and Fox [28] found income as a determining factor only among children and adults. Andersen and Benham [29] and Richardson [30] showed how financing method influence the lower-class healthcare. Particularly Andersen and Benham [29] shows positive impact of insurance coverage on healthcare demand by low-income groups. Working with the social psychological approach Stoeckle, Zola and Davidson [31] showed how patient’s knowledge and beliefs about his/her symptoms, expectations regarding health services and understanding about need for professional care influence his/her treatment seeking. Bloom and Wilson [32] also focused patient-practitioner relationships in explaining demand for healthcare. We define our objective function incorporating our theoretical understanding and empirical deduction as:

 d_{i}=-\alpha \left ( y_{i}-h_{i} \right )+\gamma X_{i}+\Omega q_{jj} 

Intuitively workers are likely to delay treatment, d, up to a period beyond which his/her health condition, X3, can no more tolerate the health deterioration given that they maximize the difference between return from investment in treatmentand their loss of earnings in that period. If we assume that health investments completely revive worker illness or injury, then the treatment cost for a specific illness or injury, h_{i} is required to regain worker i’s daily earnings, y_{i}. The term, \left (y_{i}- h_{i} \right ), therefore, indicates the benefit from treatment. Age, level of education, gender and need for regular medication are the health indicators \left ( X_{i} \right ) included. Health, precisely health deficits, has close relationship to age [33] while education and income have significant influence on healthcare seeking [34]. Women and children are often having significant higher delay. Pre-existing health issues make people more concerned about their condition [2]. A set of person specific control variables like marital status, injury as a serious type of illness, respiratory disease as a long term illness and whether he/she received treatment from a formal healthcare provider is considered in X. Chen, Rizzo, and Rodriguez [2] considered marital status of the patient as a control variable when they were examining influence of cost issues on treatment delays. Researches on cancer, urinary diseases and as such found more patients reporting in delayed manner due to different socioeconomic factors [35,24]. Rucker, Brennan, and Burstin [12] showed that treatment delay decreases significantly depending on patient’s perception about seriousness. We have included whether a person is suffering any respiratory disease as this often requires a long-term treatment contrary to injuries that may force rushed visits to healthcare centers. Rucker, Brennan, and Burstin [12] also showed that patients make delay if they do not have a regular physician. A community variable qij identifies whether the worker i is working in a rural location (j = 1 if works in a rural area, 0 otherwise). People show differentiated behaviors towards healthcare seeking based on rural-urban differences. First, healthcare facilities are mainly urban centered. Second, physician absenteeism, faulty facilities and deficiency of treatment tools and medicine are common in rural care centers.

Endogeneity issues

The supply side of health care service suffers a great degree of asymmetric information as physicians solely determine the amount of care needed. However, this could be a possible source of biasness in any attempts of examining health care demand in Bangladesh. First, doctors’ decisions about medical care are often influenced by the socioeconomic status of their patients. Second, there can be a general mistrust about the efficiency of doctor’s opinion (both cost and outcome) among patients. Bangladesh records high and fast accelerating health tourisms. Also, wealthy people rarely trust the public health care service. Thus, the interaction between health seeking behaviour and benefit from treatment is likely to be influenced by patient’s perception about healthcare service, workplace dynamics and community attitude towards health. Because we have included only the working people the health behavior of co-workers should be the strongest [36]. According to Rucker, Brennan, and Burstin [12] personal belief about seriousness of a disease, perception about need for treatment and confidence on healthcare service are key factors for treatment delay. Not only that peer effects contribute majorly in constructing individual perception but also influence different workplace constraints that may defer treatment. The problem is that in one hand the ability to perceive and the earning capability are closely related and in the other information from the peers about healthcare providers’ quality, care process, drug, and as such have impact on treatment cost. In order to address this likely endogeneity in our model where the dependent variable is categorical, we designed a two-stage residual inclusion (2SRI) regression method following Terza, Basu, and Rathouz [37]. IV Probit and Bivariate Probit are two popular methods for correcting endogeneity in probabilistic models, the first one works better when endogenous variable is continuous and the second one is applied to models without proper instrument. However, none of these methods are applicable to models with categorical dependent variable. 2SRI and Bivariate Probit were compared in Galárraga et al. [3], finding satisfactory results from both. We define the auxiliary function as:

Treatment benefit = g(age, gender, level of education, locality, W)+X_{U}

where W is the instrument(s) and X_{U} is the residual. The outcome regression will be:

d=f\left ( Treatment benefit,X,q, X_{U} \right )+e

Galárraga et al. [3] used an asset index as a proxy for household wealth and an area specific deprivation index to control well-being at the local level when they were examining appropriateness of health insurance among Mexican poor. We have used two variables: a dummy ‘test’ that takes the value 1 if the worker had to go through any pathological laboratory test during treatment and 0 otherwise; and a continuous variable ‘travel time’ that measures the travel time to the healthcare provider. Medical check-up expresses the severity of the problem along with worker’s awareness. However, tests are done after first visit to physician or healthcare provider. Travel time expresses the transportation constraint and thereby shows worker’s unwillingness to visit healthcare provider. Unfortunately, the auxiliary function can be a secondary source of endogeneity due to its resemblance to wage function. It has a Mincer [38] type wage – human capital gradient that suffers unknown ability, household optimization and measurement impacts [39]. Including proxy measures through education of parents or spouses, physical health status, nutrition, and so on [40,41] can be one remedy of this problem. Parental education, occupation, family size, distance to school, ownership of assets and as such are used as instruments by several researchers to address endogeneity problem through instrumental regression technique [42]. We have used current market value of residence as a proxy variable for level of education based on both informal method of R-squared criteria and a penalized likelihood test [43 48]. However, because of limited options we only had to compare the selected proxy against parental education.

Variable description

More than 72% of Bangladeshi ill workers take the risk of not rushing to healthcare centers. Almost 30% of them were found making delays beyond 3 days and around 21% wait more than 5 days. Among 7602 workers who have received treatment due to illness or injury the average daily income was about BDT? 319 and cost of treatment was about BDT 825. Their average age was more than 29 years, more than 52% of them were male, more than 60% were married and more than 42% required any medicine regularly. 457 of these workers were suffering from any respiratory diseases while 212 were injured. More than 36% workers received treatment from formal healthcare center, more than 43% had pathological laboratory tests and more than 64% were working in rural areas. More than 11% could not reach any healthcare within 1 hour. Around 43% workers were illiterate, 16% had received primary education and 30% had completed secondary school. Most of the workers live in cheap houses. About 2177 lived in houses worth less than BDT 100000.

1US \$ =77.47BDT\left ( 2016 \right )

RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

Table 1 presents the average marginal effects after 2SRI for our multinomial logistic regression model.

Table 1: Average Marginal Effects after 2SRI for Multinomial Logistic Regression on Self Determined Delay in treatment.

Health care seeking:

Immediately

Soon

Late

Very late

Benefit from treatment (BDT)

-5.5E-05***

9.54E-05***

9.14E-06

-4.9E-05***

(9.28E-06)

(1.03E-05)

(6.48E-06)

(5.76E-06)

 Age (years)

-1.9E-03***

2.3E-04

8.9E-04***

7.3E-04***

(3.9E-04)

(4.02E-04)

(2.3E-04)

(2.3E-04)

Current market value of house (BDT, proxy for education)

-2.9E-03

0.01***

-0.01*

-0.01*

(4.7E-03)

(4.7E-03)

(2.9E-03)

(3.06E-03)

Gender (= 1 if male, 0 otherwise)

-0.03***

3.6E-03

0.02**

0.01*

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

Need regular medication (= 1 yes, 0 otherwise)

0.02

-0.04***

4.4E-03

0.01*

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

Marital Status (= 1 if married, 0 otherwise)

0.05***

0.01

-0.03**

-0.03***

(0.01)

(0.02)

(0.01)

(0.01)

Illness type: Injury (= 1 if injured, 0 otherwise)

0.23***

-0.16***

4.3E-03

-0.08**

(0.03)

(0.04)

(0.02)

(0.03)

Illness type: Respiratory diseases (= 1 if resp. ill, 0

otherwise)

-0.02

-0.01

-0.01

0.04***

(0.02)

(0.03)

(0.02)

(0.01)

Treated by formal care provider (= 1 yes, 0 = otherwise)

-0.06***

-0.07***

0.03***

0.10***

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

Location dummy (= 1 if rural, 0 otherwise)

-0.03**

-0.01

0.01

0.03***

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

(0.01)

4.03E-05***

-6.9E-05***

-1.3E-05**

4.23E-05***

(9.52E-06)

(1.08E-05)

(6.65E-06)

(5.98E-06)

*, ** & *** represents level of significance at 10%, 5% & 1% respectively. Robust standard errors are in parenthesis.

As per the optimization rule for our discrete dynamic model the benefit from treatment appears to be very close to zero in each period. It is highly significant for workers who seek healthcare immediately, soon or very late. Workers may find it beneficial, either for regaining income or for cost of treatment, to choose the ‘soon’ or ‘vary late’ options without choosing ‘late’. Aged workers are more reluctant to visit healthcare provider early. Rucker, Brennan and Burstin [12] showed an increased urge for healthcare only among old people (beyond 65 years). However, the impact of age on healthcare delay is minimal. Current market value of the residence, which is the proxy for the level of worker’s education, shows highly significant desire for educated people to wait a little before seeking healthcare. If all workers were educated than there would be 1 percent more demand for healthcare within first two days of any illness symptoms. Simultaneously educated people are reluctant to make too late to visit physician for medical advice. Male workers are not interested in quick treatment. This may be due to their work responsibilities or perception about natural healing as mentioned by Rucker, Brennan and Burstin [12].

This gender biasness also explains extended household responsibilities for female workers. Workers needing regular medication are more likely to be very late in seeking treatment. This can be an indication of dissatisfaction of care takers. Alternatively, this can be due to their desire to get treated by the regular physician [12]. If all the workers were married there would be 5 percent more chances that they would immediately go to a healthcare provider following any illness symptom. This reflects the impact of responsibility towards family. The married people dislike making delay in treatment. Our two illness type control variables provide strong support to our model. Injured working people are highly motivated to visit healthcare provider immediately. If all ill workers were injured, then the immediate healthcare seeking would rise by 23 percent. Also injured workers will never agree to be very late in seeking healthcare. In contrary, workers suffering respiratory diseases try their best to wait for natural healing. Bangladesh being a tropical country, people are habituated to cold, cough, sore throat, asthma, and other respiratory diseases. Thus, it is not unusual that workers remain reluctant to visit physicians for any respiratory disease symptoms. Formal treatment takes time. It can be that formal healthcare is suffering serious service shortage in Bangladesh. It can also be true that workers try other informal and rudimentary methods or wait for natural healing before seeking formal healthcare.

Rural people are usually very late in seeking healthcare. A similar unwillingness to immediate treatment supports a strict division between rural and urban areas of Bangladesh. May be due to supply shortage or private sector concentration in urban area, there is a gap between infrastructural development between rural and urban areas. This is causing the differences in treatment delay behaviour.

The endogeneity incorporating error term is highly significant but having a very dismal value. Relevant Durbin–Wu–Hausman F-test suggests the significant presence of endongeneity in our model at the one percent level (Table 1).

The probability of visiting healthcare favors soon in comparison to all other category if benefit of treatment is considered. Same is true for house value, which is the proxy for education. Probability of visiting late or very late favors aged workers slightly, about 1% more than visiting soon. Male workers are 17% more likely to seek healthcare late than seeking soon. They also have 11% more chances of becoming very late in seeking treatment compared to doing it soon. Workers receiving regular medication are more than 25% probable to visit healthcare centers very late compared to going soon.

A married worker has 14% more probability to visit a healthcare center immediately rather than making delay, whereas he/she has about 25% less chances to visit very late compared to soon. The chances of receiving formal treatment is almost 57% higher if a worker makes a late visit rather than going soon to a healthcare center. The chances are almost double than soon if a worker turns up for formal treatment very late. A worker having injury is more than twice likely to immediately turning up to any healthcare facility than soon, but if having a respiratory disease than the probability to become very late is 44% more than the probability of going soon. Workers from rural areas are 40% more likely to be very late in visiting any healthcare center than going soon. They have 13% probability to do it lately rather than soon.

We have checked our results using eye problems as a replacement of respiratory diseases and found similar results. However, replacing injuries with fever did not yield significant results for illness controls. Sargan test for over-identification and Anderson LR test for IV relevance are significant. We also performed IV Probit regression finding minimal changes in results, e.g., benefit of treatment also became significant in late option, regular treatment became significant in both immediate and very late options, and as such. The instrumental variable test rejects the exogeneity in the model. We found that a multinomial logistic regression ignoring the endogeneity problem over emphasizes the benefit of treatment.

CONCLUSION

Work related injury and illness is a core reason for workers’ misery, production inefficiency, emergency health-care demand, household poverty and as such. Unfortunately, still a huge number of workers are requiring medical help due to work related injuries and illnesses every day. For more to concern, a great part of these ill or injured workers do not get proper treatment partly because of delaying to visit any healthcare center. Workers in Bangladesh often delay their treatment as they try to optimize their benefit considering out-of-pocket healthcare expenditures and earnings. Though workers prefer to have healthcare suggestions within one or two days their financial and work-related barriers may cause greater delays. A general reluctance to visit healthcare immediately reflects workplace constraints whereas confidence on the healthcare service is also questionable. Government should step forward to initiate policies like health insurance for earners, workplace health safety provisions, transportation facilities, treatment subsidies, better monitoring over health services and as such to encourage quick visits to healthcare centers.

Workers have to wait long periods if they desire formal treatment or want to see a regular doctor. Moreover, workers from rural areas face really long periods before receiving any healthcare. Hence, the government should take intensive plans to improve health infrastructure and increase proper healthcare service all over the country.

Workers’ misperception about natural healing and/or misunderstanding symptoms may cause a long delay threatening their recovery. Education provides better signals to workers. Public policies helping educational attainments and health awareness should be supportive to prevent treatment delay.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

I like to express my gratitude to unanimous reviewers and editor for their valuable suggestions. I am also thankful to my colleagues Dr. Mohammad Rafiqul Islam, Dr. Mohammad Abdul Munim Joarder and Nazmunnessa Bakth, Department of Economics, Shahjalal University of Science & Technology, Sylhet, Bangladesh, for their suggestions and supports.

REFERENCES

1. Abuduxike G, A?ut Ö, Vaizo?lu SA, Cali S. Health-Seeking Behaviors and its Determinants: A Facility-Based Cross-Sectional Study in the Turkish Republic of Northern Cyprus. Int J Health Policy Manag. 2020; 9: 240-249.

2. Chen J, Rizzo JA, Rodriguez HP. The Health Effects of Cost-Related Treatment Delays. American Journal of Medical Quality. 2011; 26: 261-271.

3. Galárraga O, Sosa-Rubí SG, Salinas-Rodríguez A, Sesma-Vázquez S. Health insurance for the poor: impact on catastrophic and out-of pocket health expenditures in Mexico. J Health Econ. 2010; 11: 437 447.

4. Tipping G, Segall M. Health Care Seeking Behaviour in Developing Countries: an annotated bibliography and literature review. Development Bibliography. 1995; 12. Institute of Development Studies, Sussex University.

5. Mackian S, Bedri N, Lovel H. Up the garden path and over the edge: where might health-seeking behaviour take us?. Health Policy Plan. 2004; 19: 137-146.

6. Ahmed SCM, Bhuiya A. Micro-Credit and emotional WellBeing: Experience of Poor Rural Women from Matlab, Bangladesh World Development. 2001; 29: 1957-1966.

7. Latunji OO, Akinyemi OO. Factors influencing health-seeking behaviour among civil servants in Ibadan, Nigeria. Ann Ib Postgrad Med. 2018; 16: 52-60.

8. Andaleeb SS. Service quality in public and private hospitals in urban Bangladesh: a comparative study. Health Policy. 2000; 53: 25-37.

9. Rahman MM, Shahidullah M, Shahiduzzaman M, Rashid HA. Quality of health care from patient perspectives. Bangladesh Medical Research Council Bulletin. 2002; 28: 87-96.

10. Conner M, Norman P. Predicting Health Behaviours: research and practice with social cognition models. Open University Press, Buckingham. 1996a.

11. Conner M, Norman P. The Role of Social Cognition in Health Behaviours. In Conner M, Norman P. (eds) (1996a) Predicting Health Behaviours: research and practice with social cognition models. Open University Press, Buckingham. 1996b; 1-22.

12. Rucker DW, Brennan TA, Burstin HR. Delay in seeking emergency care. Academic Emergency Medicine. 2001; 8: 163-169.

13. Bangladesh Health Bulletin, Management Information System. Directorate General of Health Services. Ministry of Health and Family Welfare. Government of the People’s Republic of Bangladesh: Dhaka, Bangladesh, 2007 and 2017.

14. Joarder T, Chaudhury TZ, Mannan I. Universal Health Coverage in Bangladesh: Activities, Challenges, and Suggestions. Advances in Public Health. 2019; 2019.

15. Public health services utilization study. Health Economics Unit, Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, Government of Bangladesh. 2003: 63-71.

16. Ricardo ABD, Cortez R, Hussmann K, Pantoja RR, Valaydon B, Zaman S. Comparative advantages of public and private providers in Bangladesh. World Bank. Bangladesh Development Series. 2005. Dhaka: South Asia Human Development Unit, World Bank Office: 1-75.

17. Cockcroft A, Milne D, Anderson N. Bangladesh health and population sector programme: third service delivery survey 2003: final report. Ottawa: CIET Canada. 2004; xxiii, 85.

18. Kumar N. Over 50% medical tourists to India are from Bangladesh. Sunday Guardian. News Published on August 4, 2018, 5:48 pm.

19. Finkelstein A, Luttmer EF, Notowidigdo MJ. What good is wealth without health? The effect of health on the marginal utility of consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association. 2013; 11: 221-258.

20. Schünemann J, Strulik H, Trimborn T. Going from bad to worse: Adaptation to poor health, health spending, longevity, and the value of life. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 2017; 140: 130 146.

21. Clausen A, Strub C. A General and Intuitive Envelope Theorem. ESE Discussion Papers 274, Edinburgh School of Economics, University of Edinburgh. 2016.

22. Iskhakov F, Jørgensen TH, Rust J, Schjerning B. The endogenous grid method for discrete-continuous dynamic choice models with (or without) taste shocks. Quantitative Economics. 2017; 8: 317-365.

23. Romay-Barja M, Cano J, Ncogo P, Nseng G, Santana-Morales MA, Valladares B, et al. Determinants of delay in malaria care-seeking behaviour for children 15 years and under in Bata district, Equatorial Guinea. Malaria Journal. 2016; 15: 187.

24. Wu C, Sun T, Guan X, Wang K. Predicting delay to treatment of urinary incontinence among urban community-dwelling women in China. International Journal of Nursing Sciences. 2015; 2: 34-38.

25. Anderson JG. Health services utilization: framework and review. Health Serv Res. 1973; 8: 184-199.

26. Andersen RM, Anderson OW. A Decade of Health Services: Social Survey Trends in Use and Expenditure. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 1967.

27. Anderson OW, Andersen RM. Patterns of Use of Health Services. In Freeman HE, Levine S, Reeder LG (eds.) Handbook of Medical Sociology, 2d ed., p. 386. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. 1972.

28. Bice TW, Eichhorn RL, Fox PD. Socioeconomic status and use of physician services: A reconsideration. Med Care. 1972; 10: 261-271.

29. Andersen R, Benham L. Factors Affecting the Relationship between Family Income and Medical Care Consumption. In Klarman, H. E. (ed.), Empirical Studies in Health Economics, p. 92. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press. 1970.

30. Richardson WC. Measuring the urban poor’s use of physicians’ services in response to illness episodes. Med. Care. 1970; 8: 132.

31. Stoeckle J, Zola IK, Davidson GE. On Going to see the doctor: The contributions of the patient to the decision to seek medical aid. J Chron Dis. 1963; 16: 975-989.

32. Bloom SW, Wilson RN. Patient-Practitioner Relationships. In Freeman HE, Levine S, Reeder, LG. (eds.) Handbook of Medical Sociology. 2d ed., p. 315. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. 1972.

33. Abeliansky A, Strulik H. Hungry Children Age Faster. cege Discussion Papers, Number 322, September 21, 2017.

34. Li X, Deng L, Yang H, Wang H. Effect of socioeconomic status on the healthcare-seeking behaviour of migrant workers in China. PLoS ONE. 2020; 15: e0237867.

35. Fedewa SA, Edge SB, Stewart AK, Halpern MT, Marlow NM, Ward EM. Rae and ethnicity are associated with delays in breast cancer treatment (2003-2006). J Health Care Poor Underserved. 2011; 22: 128-141.

36. Pruckner GJ, Schober T, Zocher K. The company you keep: health behaviour among work peers. The European Journal of Health Economics. 2020; 21: 251-259.

37. Terza JV, Basu A, Rathouz PJ. Two-Stage Residual Inclusion Estimation: Addressing Endogeneity in Health Econometric Modeling. J Health Econ. 2008; 27: 531-543.

38. Mincer J. Schooling, experience, and earnings. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper. 1974; Cambridge, Mass., U.S.A.: National Bureau of Economic Research.

39. Strauss J, Thomas D. Wages, schooling and background: Investments in men and women in urban Brazil. Yale University Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 649, 1991. New Haven, Conn., U.S.A.: Economic Growth Center.

40. Lam D, Schoeni RF. Effects of family background on earnings and returns to schooling: Evidence from Brazil. Journal of Political Economy. 1993; 101: 710-740.

41. Thomas D, Strauss J. Health and wages: Evidence on men and women in urban Brazil. Journal of Econometrics. 1997; 77: 159-185.

42. Maluccio J. Endogeneity of schooling in the wage function: Evidence from the rural Philippines. FCND discussion paper no. 54, 1998; Food Consumption and Nutrition Division, IFPRI.

43. Mitru? C, Bratu, MS. A procedure for selecting the best proxy variable used in predicting the consumer prices index in Romania. Procedia Economics and Finance. 2014; 10: 178-184.

44. Begum T, Rahman A, Jahan N, Sarker Md, Mustafa A, Ahmed S. Bangladesh National Health Accounts 1997 – 2012. Health Economics Unit, Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, Government of the People’s Republic of Bangladesh, 2015.

45. Center for Occupational and Environmental Health. Manchester, UK: University of Manchester; 2007.

46. Jahangir AMK, Ahmed S, MacLennan M, Sarker AR, Sultana M, Rahman H. Benefit incidence analysis of healthcare in Bangladesh-equity matters for universal health coverage. Health Policy and Planning. 2017; 32: 359-365.

47. Park K. Park’s Textbook of Preventive and Social Medicine. 21sted. New Delhi: 2011; 744.

48. Strulik H. An economic theory of depression and its impact on health behavior and longevity, cege Discussion Papers, No. 337, 2018. University of Göttingen, Center for European, Governance and Economic Development Research (cege), Göttingen,

Hasanuzzaman S (2020) Economic and Clinical Covariates of Workers’ Delayed Treatment Seeking Behavior in Bangladesh. Ann Biom Biostat 5(2): 1037.

Received : 11 Nov 2020
Accepted : 11 Dec 2020
Published : 14 Dec 2020
Journals
Annals of Otolaryngology and Rhinology
ISSN : 2379-948X
Launched : 2014
JSM Schizophrenia
Launched : 2016
Journal of Nausea
Launched : 2020
JSM Internal Medicine
Launched : 2016
JSM Hepatitis
Launched : 2016
JSM Oro Facial Surgeries
ISSN : 2578-3211
Launched : 2016
Journal of Human Nutrition and Food Science
ISSN : 2333-6706
Launched : 2013
JSM Regenerative Medicine and Bioengineering
ISSN : 2379-0490
Launched : 2013
JSM Spine
ISSN : 2578-3181
Launched : 2016
Archives of Palliative Care
ISSN : 2573-1165
Launched : 2016
JSM Nutritional Disorders
ISSN : 2578-3203
Launched : 2017
Annals of Neurodegenerative Disorders
ISSN : 2476-2032
Launched : 2016
Journal of Fever
ISSN : 2641-7782
Launched : 2017
JSM Bone Marrow Research
ISSN : 2578-3351
Launched : 2016
JSM Mathematics and Statistics
ISSN : 2578-3173
Launched : 2014
Journal of Autoimmunity and Research
ISSN : 2573-1173
Launched : 2014
JSM Arthritis
ISSN : 2475-9155
Launched : 2016
JSM Head and Neck Cancer-Cases and Reviews
ISSN : 2573-1610
Launched : 2016
JSM General Surgery Cases and Images
ISSN : 2573-1564
Launched : 2016
JSM Anatomy and Physiology
ISSN : 2573-1262
Launched : 2016
JSM Dental Surgery
ISSN : 2573-1548
Launched : 2016
Annals of Emergency Surgery
ISSN : 2573-1017
Launched : 2016
Annals of Mens Health and Wellness
ISSN : 2641-7707
Launched : 2017
Journal of Preventive Medicine and Health Care
ISSN : 2576-0084
Launched : 2018
Journal of Chronic Diseases and Management
ISSN : 2573-1300
Launched : 2016
Annals of Vaccines and Immunization
ISSN : 2378-9379
Launched : 2014
JSM Heart Surgery Cases and Images
ISSN : 2578-3157
Launched : 2016
Annals of Reproductive Medicine and Treatment
ISSN : 2573-1092
Launched : 2016
JSM Brain Science
ISSN : 2573-1289
Launched : 2016
JSM Biomarkers
ISSN : 2578-3815
Launched : 2014
JSM Biology
ISSN : 2475-9392
Launched : 2016
Archives of Stem Cell and Research
ISSN : 2578-3580
Launched : 2014
Annals of Clinical and Medical Microbiology
ISSN : 2578-3629
Launched : 2014
JSM Pediatric Surgery
ISSN : 2578-3149
Launched : 2017
Journal of Memory Disorder and Rehabilitation
ISSN : 2578-319X
Launched : 2016
JSM Tropical Medicine and Research
ISSN : 2578-3165
Launched : 2016
JSM Head and Face Medicine
ISSN : 2578-3793
Launched : 2016
JSM Cardiothoracic Surgery
ISSN : 2573-1297
Launched : 2016
JSM Bone and Joint Diseases
ISSN : 2578-3351
Launched : 2017
JSM Bioavailability and Bioequivalence
ISSN : 2641-7812
Launched : 2017
JSM Atherosclerosis
ISSN : 2573-1270
Launched : 2016
Journal of Genitourinary Disorders
ISSN : 2641-7790
Launched : 2017
Journal of Fractures and Sprains
ISSN : 2578-3831
Launched : 2016
Journal of Autism and Epilepsy
ISSN : 2641-7774
Launched : 2016
Annals of Marine Biology and Research
ISSN : 2573-105X
Launched : 2014
JSM Health Education & Primary Health Care
ISSN : 2578-3777
Launched : 2016
JSM Communication Disorders
ISSN : 2578-3807
Launched : 2016
Annals of Musculoskeletal Disorders
ISSN : 2578-3599
Launched : 2016
Annals of Virology and Research
ISSN : 2573-1122
Launched : 2014
JSM Renal Medicine
ISSN : 2573-1637
Launched : 2016
Journal of Muscle Health
ISSN : 2578-3823
Launched : 2016
JSM Genetics and Genomics
ISSN : 2334-1823
Launched : 2013
JSM Anxiety and Depression
ISSN : 2475-9139
Launched : 2016
Clinical Journal of Heart Diseases
ISSN : 2641-7766
Launched : 2016
Annals of Medicinal Chemistry and Research
ISSN : 2378-9336
Launched : 2014
JSM Pain and Management
ISSN : 2578-3378
Launched : 2016
JSM Women's Health
ISSN : 2578-3696
Launched : 2016
Clinical Research in HIV or AIDS
ISSN : 2374-0094
Launched : 2013
Journal of Endocrinology, Diabetes and Obesity
ISSN : 2333-6692
Launched : 2013
Journal of Substance Abuse and Alcoholism
ISSN : 2373-9363
Launched : 2013
JSM Neurosurgery and Spine
ISSN : 2373-9479
Launched : 2013
Journal of Liver and Clinical Research
ISSN : 2379-0830
Launched : 2014
Journal of Drug Design and Research
ISSN : 2379-089X
Launched : 2014
JSM Clinical Oncology and Research
ISSN : 2373-938X
Launched : 2013
JSM Bioinformatics, Genomics and Proteomics
ISSN : 2576-1102
Launched : 2014
JSM Chemistry
ISSN : 2334-1831
Launched : 2013
Journal of Trauma and Care
ISSN : 2573-1246
Launched : 2014
JSM Surgical Oncology and Research
ISSN : 2578-3688
Launched : 2016
Annals of Food Processing and Preservation
ISSN : 2573-1033
Launched : 2016
Journal of Radiology and Radiation Therapy
ISSN : 2333-7095
Launched : 2013
JSM Physical Medicine and Rehabilitation
ISSN : 2578-3572
Launched : 2016
Annals of Clinical Pathology
ISSN : 2373-9282
Launched : 2013
Annals of Cardiovascular Diseases
ISSN : 2641-7731
Launched : 2016
Journal of Behavior
ISSN : 2576-0076
Launched : 2016
Annals of Clinical and Experimental Metabolism
ISSN : 2572-2492
Launched : 2016
Clinical Research in Infectious Diseases
ISSN : 2379-0636
Launched : 2013
JSM Microbiology
ISSN : 2333-6455
Launched : 2013
Journal of Urology and Research
ISSN : 2379-951X
Launched : 2014
Journal of Family Medicine and Community Health
ISSN : 2379-0547
Launched : 2013
Annals of Pregnancy and Care
ISSN : 2578-336X
Launched : 2017
JSM Cell and Developmental Biology
ISSN : 2379-061X
Launched : 2013
Annals of Aquaculture and Research
ISSN : 2379-0881
Launched : 2014
Clinical Research in Pulmonology
ISSN : 2333-6625
Launched : 2013
Journal of Immunology and Clinical Research
ISSN : 2333-6714
Launched : 2013
Annals of Forensic Research and Analysis
ISSN : 2378-9476
Launched : 2014
JSM Biochemistry and Molecular Biology
ISSN : 2333-7109
Launched : 2013
Annals of Breast Cancer Research
ISSN : 2641-7685
Launched : 2016
Annals of Gerontology and Geriatric Research
ISSN : 2378-9409
Launched : 2014
Journal of Sleep Medicine and Disorders
ISSN : 2379-0822
Launched : 2014
JSM Burns and Trauma
ISSN : 2475-9406
Launched : 2016
Chemical Engineering and Process Techniques
ISSN : 2333-6633
Launched : 2013
Annals of Clinical Cytology and Pathology
ISSN : 2475-9430
Launched : 2014
JSM Allergy and Asthma
ISSN : 2573-1254
Launched : 2016
Journal of Neurological Disorders and Stroke
ISSN : 2334-2307
Launched : 2013
Annals of Sports Medicine and Research
ISSN : 2379-0571
Launched : 2014
JSM Sexual Medicine
ISSN : 2578-3718
Launched : 2016
Annals of Vascular Medicine and Research
ISSN : 2378-9344
Launched : 2014
JSM Biotechnology and Biomedical Engineering
ISSN : 2333-7117
Launched : 2013
Journal of Hematology and Transfusion
ISSN : 2333-6684
Launched : 2013
JSM Environmental Science and Ecology
ISSN : 2333-7141
Launched : 2013
Journal of Cardiology and Clinical Research
ISSN : 2333-6676
Launched : 2013
JSM Nanotechnology and Nanomedicine
ISSN : 2334-1815
Launched : 2013
Journal of Ear, Nose and Throat Disorders
ISSN : 2475-9473
Launched : 2016
JSM Ophthalmology
ISSN : 2333-6447
Launched : 2013
Journal of Pharmacology and Clinical Toxicology
ISSN : 2333-7079
Launched : 2013
Annals of Psychiatry and Mental Health
ISSN : 2374-0124
Launched : 2013
Medical Journal of Obstetrics and Gynecology
ISSN : 2333-6439
Launched : 2013
Annals of Pediatrics and Child Health
ISSN : 2373-9312
Launched : 2013
JSM Clinical Pharmaceutics
ISSN : 2379-9498
Launched : 2014
JSM Foot and Ankle
ISSN : 2475-9112
Launched : 2016
JSM Alzheimer's Disease and Related Dementia
ISSN : 2378-9565
Launched : 2014
Journal of Addiction Medicine and Therapy
ISSN : 2333-665X
Launched : 2013
Journal of Veterinary Medicine and Research
ISSN : 2378-931X
Launched : 2013
Annals of Public Health and Research
ISSN : 2378-9328
Launched : 2014
Annals of Orthopedics and Rheumatology
ISSN : 2373-9290
Launched : 2013
Journal of Clinical Nephrology and Research
ISSN : 2379-0652
Launched : 2014
Annals of Community Medicine and Practice
ISSN : 2475-9465
Launched : 2014
JSM Clinical Case Reports
ISSN : 2373-9819
Launched : 2013
Journal of Cancer Biology and Research
ISSN : 2373-9436
Launched : 2013
Journal of Surgery and Transplantation Science
ISSN : 2379-0911
Launched : 2013
Journal of Dermatology and Clinical Research
ISSN : 2373-9371
Launched : 2013
JSM Gastroenterology and Hepatology
ISSN : 2373-9487
Launched : 2013
Annals of Nursing and Practice
ISSN : 2379-9501
Launched : 2014
JSM Dentistry
ISSN : 2333-7133
Launched : 2013
Author Information X